What’s next: The ongoing urban exodus
What’s next: The ongoing urban exodus
- June 15, 2021
- Remote worker migration will depress home prices in big cities and raise them in suburbs, says UCI economist
Many employees have come to prefer working from home after being forced to do so more than a year ago when the pandemic started. By some estimates, at least one-quarter of employees will still be working remotely multiple days a week at the end of 2021. For those whose jobs allow it, being untethered from the office might mean moving farther away from it – by a few miles or a few hundred.
The National Bureau of Economic Research recently published a white paper by Jan Brueckner, UCI Distinguished Professor of economics, and his colleagues Matthew Kahn and Gary Lin at Johns Hopkins University considering the possible effects that ongoing remote work may have on housing markets, especially in the more densely populated and pricey urban areas. Brueckner shares his insights here.
Listen in to the UCI Podcast with Jan Brueckner as he explains how the pandemic has disrupted housing markets and why work from home favors the suburbs.
---
You suggest that as more people have the opportunity to work from home, we’ll see
people move either farther into suburbia or to entirely different, less expensive
cities. Why?
If workers can keep their well-paying jobs and move to a cheaper city, their incomes
will go further. However, such a move might entail a sacrifice of amenities (good
weather, etc.) that would need to be considered. For those workers who remain in their
original city, the reduction in commuting costs due to working from home (going to
the office only once a week, say) makes the suburbs – where housing is cheaper on
a per-square-foot basis – more attractive than before. As a result, working from home
may lead to greater suburbanization.
What cities might we expect to be most affected by these shifts?
We would expect to see impacts in expensive cities with large shares of white-collar
jobs that pay well and allow working from home. Such cities would include New York,
San Francisco, Boston and Seattle. We expect people to move out of these cities –
either into outlying suburban areas or to entirely different cities or even states.
So … it could become affordable to live in San Francisco again?
Possibly.
On the flip side, where do you expect to see people flock to?
We’ve heard in the media about migration from California to Austin, Texas, which is
relatively cheap and offers less of an amenity sacrifice compared to coastal locations.
The same is true for Boise, Idaho, which is in the news a lot. Migration data a few
years hence will give a more complete picture.
Is this going to mean more gentrification in some cities?
In one sense, it’s exactly the reverse. The prediction is that many well-paid residents
will be leaving the country’s premier cities, allowing more room for the less affluent.
Gentrification may increase in the receiving cities as immigrants arrive, but gentrification
pressure is lower in many of these places and thus less of a concern for poorer central
city residents.
You mention that “the economy still has a long way to go before reaching the new predicted
equilibrium.” What kind of time horizon do you envision?
If our predictions are correct, we’d expect these changes to be complete within a
decade. There are a number of caveats, however. Our predictions assume that CEOs will
tolerate remote work from another city and not penalize those who do it. The Wall
Street Journal, however, recently ran a story that casts doubt on this assumption.
The issue partly hinges on whether remote workers can maintain their productivity,
a concern discounted by some media reports saying that workers feel more productive
remotely. A further question involves integration of new employees into an organization
that relies on remote work. New employees may have trouble forging bonds and creating
a rapport with their colleagues.
As we approach this new equilibrium, what are some other changes we can expect to
see?
Intercity relocation will depress house prices and rents in cities that lose population
while raising them in the receiving cities. Intracity relocation will push prices
up in the suburbs. These changes will, in turn, affect property tax revenues across
and within cities.
-Christine Byrd for UCI Social Sciences
pictured top to right: The pandemic-prompted phenomenon of working from home could
make the choice of where to live far less dependent on where one’s employer is located.
Big cities such as Los Angeles (above, along Broadway) could lose residents to less
expensive areas. Jan Brueckner, Distinguished Professor of Economics. Steve Zylius
/ UCI
Share on:
connect with us